Reconcile This: Lessons From
The Latest Legislative Debacle
Jim Kavanagh
So the Biden administration has achieved passage of, and signed into law, its Infrastructure Bill, and its Reconciliation/Social Spending Bill, dubbed Build Back Better (BBB), has passed the House and is awaiting decision by the Senate. Watching this process play out over the past months has demonstrated, in a way that could not be more definitive, a couple of core truths about the prospects for achieving social policies that could provide socio-economic security and justice for working-class—most—Americans, let alone any kind of transformative, lasting change in socio-economic structures.
The Outer Limits
The first of those truths, which left-socialists have long understood and many more sincerely concerned progressives are finding inescapable, is that the necessary social policies will never be achieved through the extant two-party system and the normal legislative process. This is so, it is becoming hard not to acknowledge, because that process and those two parties—the Democrats (including their “progressive” squaddies and their “socialist” auxiliary) at least as much as the Republicans—are institutionally designed to be obstacles to any such reform. They are representatives of the donor caste, not of their ostensible popular constituencies.
This truth, commonplace among us marxists forever, has been
common knowledge in contemporary academic and political circles at least since
the Princeton study
of 2014, which found that, in the U.S.: “policymaking is dominated by powerful
business organizations and a small number of affluent Americans… the majority
does not rule—at least not in the causal sense of actually determining policy
outcomes,” and it was succinctly confirmed by a “moderate” Democratic president
in 2015, who said
the: U.S. “is just an oligarchy with unlimited political bribery.”
We have seen this play out blatantly in the legislative
games over the dual Infrastructure/BBB bills. Which is, as David Sirota and
Andrew Perez have
said, “an illuminating moment [that] reveals the outer limits of
possibility for corporate politics.” Without going too far into the weeds, or
denying that there are some good provisions in both bills, it’s clear that, as
David Dayen points
out with the example of broadband reform, the benefits of infrastructure
spending were systematically shifted away from “engaging in any meaningful
structural reform” and toward protecting and subsidizing extant dominant private
industries. And we all saw the social spending component reduced from 6+ to 3+
to 1+ trillion—with adamantly, cross-my-heart promised and popular programs
like a $15 minimum wage, college debt relief, free community college, prescription
drug-price negotiation, lowering Medicare eligibility age and expanding benefits,
public health insurance options, etc., all relentlessly weeded out or pruned to
the nubs “amid a flood of
industry campaign cash.”
It was all embedded, of course, in the formulaic Democratic-Party
theater of foot-stomping progressives
and rotating
villains. The
leading role in the progressive cast’s adamant promise to stand its ground
against Republicans and corporate Democrats went to Bernie Sanders, who insisted: "Let
me be clear: There will not be a bipartisan infrastructure deal without a
reconciliation bill that substantially improves the lives of working families …No
reconciliation bill, no deal.” And
"you have to have a statement which says A, B, C, D, and E is going to be
in the package and 50 members of the Senate are supporting it." And
“Let’s be crystal clear. If the bipartisan infrastructure bill is passed on its
own on Thursday, this will be in violation of an agreement …More importantly,
it will end all leverage that we have to pass a major reconciliation bill.”
The alphabet soup Bernie & Co. actually swallowed: A) The
infrastructure bill passed on its own with B) no concrete commitment to
anything, just C) a vague promise to consider, and D) all leverage was lost
before the show began, because E) Bernie and the squad are committed to the
discipline of the political framework they accept, which dictates that the
Democratic Party must be defended as the only, essentially more progressive,
bulwark against the essentially more reactionary and apocalyptically dangerous
Republican Party, and therefore F) the progressives predictably, formulaically,
end the drama, as Sirota puts it, “cit[ing] Republicans’ even worse behavior as
the reason we should all supposedly feel thankful for Democrats, even as they
are betraying their promises." Do re mi, A B C, 1 2 3.
It’s all so 2009. As when Obama repeatedly promised
and told
Congress he wouldn’t sign any healthcare bill that didn’t include a public
option, and 60 members of Congress huffed and puffed with a “sharply worded
letter,” proclaiming themselves “firm in their position that any legislation
that moves forward … for the president's signature, MUST contain a public
option” [their emphasis]. In that production of the show, Democratic Senators
like Max Baucus and Joe Lieberman played the roles now held by Manchin and
Sinema, with those sharp-penned Democratic representatives were the reluctantly
folding progressives played today by the progressive squad—with Bernie Sanders
reprising Dennis Kucinich’s role as the last holdout, laying down his guns in
the final scene to save his Captain from failure.
Then, as now, this was an entirely Democratic show and cast,
without a single Republican necessary, directed by the president (Obama and
Rahm Emanuel in 2009, whoever’s running the Biden animatronic today). Do not
let yourself swallow a story about the brave Democratic president being held
back by the evil Republicans; getting you to believe that narrative is the most
important and pernicious effect of these productions.
As I’ve said before,
that narrative is hogwash. The possibility of real progressive healthcare
reform—which would have been single-payer, but not even the half-assed “public
option”—was betrayed by Obama and conservative Democratic legislators, who
never wanted any public plan, and by compliant progressive Democratic
legislators who reneged on their sworn and signed promise not to vote for
exactly the kind of capitulation to the insurance companies Obamacare is.
Same old song today. It is the progressive constituency, not
the Republicans, who are being fought and played by the Democratic President
and Party, and it is the Democratic Party and its leadership that is the most
effective obstacle to, and must be the target of, progressives’ relentless and
unforgiving pressure for, any kind of significant social reform.
Having seen this show so many times, many, many more people now
recognize and reject the game that’s being played. At this point, the social
house is on fire, and many, many fewer people are going to feel thankful to the
Democrats for bargaining over a few cups of water, as they are betraying their
promise to bring the pumper trucks.
So, let’s hope this is indeed “an illuminating moment” that,
to rephrase Sirota’s remark for the necessary clarity and difficulty, reveals
the outer limits of possibility for American two-party capitalist politics. Because we like to think
there may arise some “anti-corporate” politics within one of those parties, but
we (better) know damn well there will be no anti-capitalist politics necessary
to solve our significant social problems from either of the two capitalist
parties and the political paradigm they enforce, no matter how many
“progressive” or “justice” or “populist” candidates are elected in either of
them.
But let’s also recognize what a fucked-up and difficult
place that leaves us in. It’s nothing unusual to recognize that any radical
socialist politics is not centered on electoral politics. But, in a modern
society, it’s also hard to conceive that a socialist, or even mildly
social-democratic politics can advance, without establishing a foothold in the normal
electoral and legislative processes of a country. It is from the reciprocal relationship
between “normal” electoral and “radical” non-electoral organizing and actions
that a socialist movement can achieve any kind of significant reform peacefully,
and build the breadth and strength of public support necessary for a
revolutionary transformation that will require revolutionary force.
In our two-party capitalist parity, there is no way to
establish such a foothold. None. We now know that there’s no essential
pro-working-class, social-democratic identity in one capitalist right-wing party
that gives it essentially “better” potential for socialist purposes than the
other capitalist right-wing party we always knew that about. We know there is no
change coming though electing “progressive” Democrats or “socialist” sheepdogs
(Bernie Sanders) who are going to persuade their colleagues of the virtue and
rationality of even the most basic ameliorative, and enormously popular, social-democratic
programs, like single-payer.
But the parties are only nodes in a system of deeply
entrenched political and ideological institutions that effectively make
anything else impossible.
So let’s start a third party! A fine idea. A People’s Party.
You mean like the Peace and Freedom Party? Or the Greens? I support it, but
I’ve also seen it.
Such a party must, of course, define itself around some core
principles and issues (the fewer the better), and one of them--the first working
task, the prerequisite for and no less substantive and important than any
other—is to create the conditions that would enable it to fairly and
effectively contest elections. A third party cannot just enter the arena where
the matador and picadors await. It must fight for changing ballot laws, for
changing campaign finance practices, for equal-time major media policies and
open, uncensored social media and internet platforms, for ranked-choice voting,
for fair, transparent voting processes that make voting easy to do and hard to manipulate
(something neither party is now interested in), etc. At the federal
level, and in every state and county.
These things are not impossible, but are very difficult. In the present hostile
context, where they disrupt the accepted model, even large sectors of the
working-class population will be suspicious of any such changes. Frankly, as
I‘ve argued previously,
I think the extant electoral system is nearly impossible to change from the
inside, and boycotting it—not just the “voting with their feet” individual
withdrawal that’s already widespread, but with a political boycott campaign organized
around that disaffection—may be the necessary first step to force it open.
More generally, the now-confirmed outer limits of
possibility for American two-party capitalist politics, the fact that our
polity is so tightly controlled, politically and ideologically, and the present
party structure so resistant to change, means that we will not get any
significant change—from “process” changes in the electoral system like ranked-choice
voting to social policies like Medicare-for-all—via legislative debate alone.
It will likely require storming the Capitol, or some similarly disruptive direct
action. Somebody’s got to get gored.
Any third party will need to explain, propagandize, and take
up that fight as a primary priority, from day one. Getting the nuts and bolts
of the electoral system in a condition that allows the party to exist politically
must be understood as a substantive founding issue. The party will only be able
to affect the larger, historically entrenched, undemocratic constitutional structures
of the government that block other substantive policies—from the Electoral
College to the Senate, the filibuster, etc.—if it has succeeded in the
prerequisite. The party organization and membership must be united in focusing
on that, unaffected by all the much-loved leftist infighting on other (e.g.,
identity-politics) issues, or it may as well go home.
To add what should be obvious: Any such party must be
committed to fighting the Democrats as much as the Republicans, must know and
embrace the fact that it will not win any election until it makes the Democrats
lose some. They’ve got to get gored. If you’re not willing to do that, go home.
So, Lesson One, in full: Necessary social policies will
never be achieved through the extant two-party system and the normal
legislative process. If you enter the ring, use your horns. Or go home.
The Inner Limits
As I said, many more people have learned that first lesson or
had it confirmed from this congressional debate, and that’s a good thing,
Lesson Two, on the other hand—though it’s one this
legislative rigamarole so obviously teaches, about an impediment that’s so
obviously central and so clearly must be overcome—is one that many of the same
people find hard to accept. Not because of any external obstacle, but because
it disrupts a framework of thought and “reality” in which they’ve found a
comfortable “progressive” niche. It’s a niche built on a false foundation, however,
in which progressives are killing themselves with constant self-cutting.
Lesson Two is: “Taxpayer money” destroys
social programs.
Let me reprise what I said in a previous article:
- There is no such thing as “taxpayer money.”
- Taxes do not pay for federal government spending. Nor does federal government “debt,” which is not that thing. No revenue is needed.
- Leftists who continue to think and say that “taxpayer dollars” must be collected to “pay for” federal government programs will continue to destroy the possibility of every universal social policy.
However one is primed to react to those statements, it is
undeniable that they speak directly to the central issue in this truly bizarre
“reconciliation”
process and in every congressional debate over social programs: How are you
going to pay for it? And the answer from every Democratic and Republican
politician, and from every progressive and leftist who does not understand or
accept these statements is the same: “With taxes.” For most political
actors across the spectrum, the money to pay for national social programs must
come from a “revenue” source outside the government—the taxpayer (corporate or
individual), from which the government gets its money and on whom the
government depends.
Those who want the programs—Bernie, the Squad, et. al.—say they
can be paid for with higher taxes on corporations and the wealthy; those who
oppose them—Manchin, Sinema, et. al.—say no you can’t, you’ll never raise taxes
enough to pay for them, taxes are already too high, we must cut back on other
programs that are paid for with taxes, etc. This is, as it always is, the
entire debate, whose terms both sides accept, that is consuming the Congress,
the Democratic Party, and the country.
How’s it going?
Really, for the purpose of achieving universal social
programs of significant, irreversible benefit, how’s this debate working out?
How does it always work out?
Whatever one’s reflexive reaction to my theses above, it is
undeniable that they change the debate, radically. If they are true, the entire
fight over where to get the money to pay for necessary social programs just
disappears.
If it is true that the federal government creates money—U. S.
dollars—by spending, which is prior to, and the source of, any taxes paid, then
“taxpayer money” doesn’t exist, the “taxpayer” is an irrelevant character for federal
spending considerations, and the debate centered around those categories is a fictional
diversion that the progressive left is wasting its time, and losing, with.
Because you cannot win a fake debate.
And it is true. Though it's been deliberately obfuscated, by
most people for a long time, the managers of the US financial system have
always known, and said, it’s true. Increasing numbers of politicians and
political actors across the spectrum know it’s true. They just don’t want to
say it.
On the right, they want people to continue believing that
our government and public welfare depends on the wealthy, conceived as
society’s breadwinners and donors who subsidize non-taxpaying “takers.” On the
left, many activists just can’t give up on the “Make the rich pay!” approach they’ve
been comfortable with, despite the fact that it reinforces all the “payers and
takers” crap and the general notion that the public sphere depends on private
wealth. They do not want to recognize that approach makes the rich an
indispensable resource we must keep around. They cannot see, or don’t want to
work with, the much more empowering attitude about the rich for the left: “We
don’t need you or your stinkin’ money.”
Of course it’s true, because money isn’t conjured up in
“taxpayers'” pockets; it is created by political decisions of the US
Congress to spend money into the economy. That money goes out as effectively
interest-free loans that are only partially paid back in taxes. Those taxes
extinguish part of the loan, turning -1s to 0s in the federal government’s
ledger. They do not pay for federal government programs, whether
aircraft carriers or child care. All those programs are “paid for”—i.e.,
funded—by congressional money-creating “appropriations.” It is not “tax
and spend”; it is spend, then tax.
The federal government does not collect revenue; it creates
money. The amount of money spent/created into the economy in a given year and
not collected back in taxes is the “deficit”—a good thing, since it would be
ridiculous to take it all back in taxes. To paraphrase Stephanie Kelton: The
government's deficit is the economy’s surplus. It would also be ridiculous to try
and take back all the money the federal government has ever created and left in the
economy—which is what’s called the “national debt.”
It’s also ridiculous to think the national “debt” is
anything like the “debt” people incur from private banks, the other
institutions federally authorized to create dollars. Unlike money created by
congressional spending, the dollars created by bank loans constitute a debt that
must be paid back fully, with interest.
Indeed, recognize that one of the reasons banksters hate
government spending, deficits, and debt is because there is a tendentially
inverse relationship between the government’s deficit/“debt” and your personal
debt to the banks. The less money the government creates/spends and leaves in
people’s and businesses’ accounts as interest-free loans never to be fully paid
back in taxes, the more people and businesses will have to turn to the banks
for loans that must be paid back with interest, to their profit. Which is why
we should have a public banking system.
For political reasons, these economic truths are swaddled in
a set of diversionary ideologies, policies, and laws—PAYGO, CBO scores, debt
ceiling, etc.—that both parties accept and endorse, which make it look like
the U.S. government must be run like a household. These serve no purpose but to
help us internalize the ruling class’s insistence that we must, and usually
can’t, “find the money” to do the things we want and need. But, unlike any
household, the U.S. government is a monetary sovereign—it creates money
and pays all its bills in the money it creates. The relevant question is never:
“Where will the government get the money?” It’s always: “What is the government
creating/spending money for” and “Where does the economy’s surplus go?” “In
whose pockets does it end up?” Those are exactly the questions leftists should
be insisting on.
Unless leftists and progressives who want robust, universal
(non-means-tested) social programs start understanding, explaining, and acting
within this paradigm, they will fail, now and forever. Really in a context
where we’ve just seen the federal government create about $6 trillion dollars—which
did not come, and will never be paid back, from “taxpayer money,” where we’ve
just seen increase on top of increase of “Defense” spending to $740 million,
with nary a peep about CBO scores or the national debt or “finding” the money, and
with the social house on fire, how is it that progressives and leftists do not
recognize the obvious truth and usefulness of this paradigm? How self-defeating
it is to allow themselves to be dragged into the ridiculous “How are you going
to pay for it?” fight that is eating away every aspect of their program no
matter how furiously Bernie waves the “Make the rich pay their fair share” flag?
“Tax the rich” is a fine idea, if it’s a call to tax the
rich because they’re too rich and therefore too powerful. Even if we
don’t eliminate, we need to limit inequality of wealth and power. I support
Eisenhower-level high—call them confiscatory—marginal tax rates (>90%, even
100%) on tiers of income above—What? $10 million? $5 million? Why not $1
million or less? Pick a number that means nobody’s going to starve and
nobody’s going to buy political power.
“Tax the rich” is a terrible idea, however, if it’s a call
to tax the rich because we need their money in order to pay for
Medicare, Social Security, or any social program. Really, a terrible
idea.
To see how crucial it is to know how the monetary system actually
works, look at the knot of confusion the Democrats are tied up in over the
State and Local Tax (SALT) deduction. They’re all a-squirm in the lovely trap
set in the Trump administration’s 2017 tax bill, which capped the federal tax deduction
for state and local taxes paid, which had been virtually limitless, at $10,000.
Why?
One cannot understand what’s at stake here, or what a
progressive position might be, unless one understands a fundamental fact about
the qualitatively different function of taxes in the different taxing
jurisdictions. The federal government does not need tax revenue to pay
for its programs, but state and local governments do. They are not
monetary sovereigns; they are not creators, but users of money, and must get it
from an external source. They need tax revenue to pay for most of the basic
services people rely on every day—from schools to running water to paved
streets.
Trump instituted the SALT cap specifically to punish Democratic
states with high state tax rates (NY, NJ, CA), with the intended effect of incentivizing
high-income people, whose taxes those states need, to move or to support local-tax-cutting
policies and candidates. It’s an anti-social effect all the way down.
In response, the senators and congresspeople from those
Democratic states want to eliminate or raise that cap. Per Trump’s indented
effect, the Democrats almost lost the governorship of reliably blue New Jersey,
because the Democrat, Murphy, was “hammered”
by “how effective [his Republican] challenger… was in playing to voters’
feelings about the state’s high taxes.” So, under pressure, such as letters
from seven Democratic governors and nearly every New York Democratic congressperson
demanding that he fully repeal the cap, Biden included in BBB a provision to raise
the SALT cap to $80,000 through 2030 before falling back to $10K.
Progressives and leftists who do not understand the U.S.
monetary system, and think federal taxes pay for federal social programs, are
now piling on to attack that provision as a “giveaway to the rich.” Raising the
cap, they say, will primarily benefit the top
2% of Americans, who are the only ones who pay over $10K in SALT. It’s a “policy that [gives] tax cuts to rich
homeowners in New Jersey, New York and California.” Actually, that’s the
language attributed
to the National Republican Congressional Committee, which, in its own
hypocritical way, seconds the dominant progressive critique of raising the SALT
cap as a “politically toxic polic[y] which penalize[s] hard working families to
reward liberal elites.” Cute.
So, how to sort out this scrum in which progressives and
leftists agree with Trump’s tax “reform,” which will advantage Republican
candidates and regressive tax policy down the line, and attack Biden and the Democratic
Congress’s reversal of it as a gift to billionaires? (Not that there’s anything
wrong with agreeing with reactionaries of either the Republican or Democratic variety,
if they’re right. Be “for
the truth, no matter who tells it.”)
The answer is that you cannot sort it out if your premise is
that both state-local and federal taxes have the same function and both levels
of government draw from the total taxes-paid pot for the same purposes. Because
they do not.
The federal SALT deduction cap will effectively become a
means, not to raise the total tax paid by the wealthy in both jurisdictions,
but to shift tax payments from the states and localities to the federal
government. That is, it will end up lowering taxes paid to the jurisdictions
that need them to pay for things, while raising taxes paid to the jurisdiction
that does not.
Whatever Trump pretended or progressives think, you’re not
getting more needed money for the federal government to pay for social programs
by setting a SALT deduction cap. The SALT deduction deprives the federal
government of nothing it needs.
The federal SALT deduction only prevents paying a second tax
on income that’s already been taxed. Of course, nobody wants to do that, and of
course the rich are going to benefit the most from eliminating it. They are the
only ones filling out federal tax forms who have already paid >$10K in state
and local taxes, which are actually used to pay for state and local services
the federal government does not provide.
The jurisdictions that use tax money to pay for services, you
see, do depend on keeping the rich around to pay that tax. Of course, the
wealthy will exploit that dependence to blackmail states by threatening to vote
for whoever will cut local taxes or to move if those taxes aren’t reduced.
Progressives who think “Tax the Rich” is a simple panacea, like
to dismiss the second possibility as remote. But those 2% who benefit the most are
precisely those who already benefit from having multiple residences around the
country. They can and will tax-shop among states. As in
“people had been migrating away from New Jersey because the cap on the
deduction meant an increase in the cost of living.” As in, I personally know
people who have done it.
Given the federal structure of our country, the SALT
deduction cap will inevitably encourage the worst kind of tax-cutting
competition among states, which will have devastating effects on basic local
services.
Isn’t it great (Please get this point!) that, unlike the
states, the federal government does not depend on those wealthy and
their taxes, and cannot be blackmailed by them. (Unless conservatives
and liberals and progressives and leftists continue to believe the “taxes pay
for federal programs” ideology through which they blackmail themselves.)
This is not a matter of whether to tax the rich. It’s a
matter of knowing who is taxing them and for what purpose, knowing when raising
unneeded-for-revenue taxes will lower needed-for-revenue taxes. It’s a matter
of understanding what a progressive tax policy means in a polity where the
central, money-creating government does not pay directly for all local
services, but money-using local governments do.
Again, if you want to tax the rich progressively at the federal
level (for the relevant purposes of controlling inequality and/or inflation), then
raise the marginal tax rates directly. But, even If we succeed in getting a 100%
federal tax on income over $1 million (for the purpose of controlling
inequality), would we not have to keep some kind of SALT deduction to
make sure states and localities got the taxes they need (for the purpose of providing
local services)?
Avoiding raising the marginal rates directly, and instead fighting
over the at-best questionably effective SALT deduction cap does not demonstrate
how tax-progressive you are, but how tax-progressive you can’t be.
With the SALT deduction cap, Trump set a trap, baited with
the sticky poison of the false and pernicious “taxpayer money” paradigm, into
which Democrats and progressives have jumped and will never get out. Easy prey.
The solution to our problems will not come from raising more
taxes for revenue. It will require a clear-eyed re-conception of tax policy as
a whole, which will involve raising some and lowering other tax rates, based on
a correct understanding of how the system works, as relevant for progressive
purposes.
Maybe a robust, effective, progressive tax policy is
something more complicated than “Tax the Rich.” It might even lead with a
demand to lower taxes on the people who are over-taxed. Maybe with, as I
have
previously
suggested,
something like: “Medicare for all and eliminate payroll taxes!”—which
would give more direct and immediate benefit to the working-class than fiddling
with the SALT shaker. But you can’t even see the possibility of that if you’re stuck
in the framework that fixates Democrats, progressives, and leftists on the need
to raise taxes—and thus keep a low SALT deduction cap—to pay for federal social
programs.
So the second lesson we have been watching unfold over the
past few months of legislative battle, for the umpteenth time, is that we are
destroying the possibility of social programs, and destroying the possibility
of even having a cogent discussion of progressive tax and spending policy, if
we continue to accept all the false assumptions underlying the “taxpayer money”
mythology.
My summary statement of the two points: 1) Two-party
capitalist electoral politics and 2) the conventional paradigm of money and
taxes are at a dead end. Dead. End.
They must be replaced. And the obstacles to doing so—institutional
and ideological—are severe.
Of course, these are not the only lessons emerging from
developments in recent US politics. There are other little things like imperialism
in general and three emerging theaters of imminent war in particular that we
had better study on. But these two, at least, are the ones that have been staring
us in the face for months in this legislative, BBB, “reconciliation” debacle.
Though many more now do understand one or the other of these
lessons, few understand or speak forthrightly about both, and no political
organization exists that is capable of effectively changing either.
Fortunately, if exhaustingly, school is never out.
___________________________
Related articles: Payroll Taxes Are the Achilles Heel of Social Security, “Taxpayer Money” Threatens Medicare-for-All (And Every Other Social Program), Joe or No?, The Party’s Over: Bernie’s Last Dance With The Dems
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments will be lightly moderated, with disfavor for personal attacks and stunning irrelevancies, and deference to the trenchant and amusing.